Defensive Strategies
of the Roman Empire
This video
will describe the strategies employed by the Roman Empire to defend its territory,
as laid out in American strategist Edward Luttwak’s Book, The Grand Strategy of the Roman Empire. Luttwak is not a full-time
historian and archaeological evidence contradicts some of his views, but at a
minimum the video illustrates his thinking on several variants of defensive
strategy, their pros and cons, and the links that exist between politics and
strategy formulation.
Generally,
an ‘optimal strategy’ is seen as one that gives the most benefit for the least
cost, but what counts as ‘benefit’ or ‘cost’ itself depends on circumstance and
the perspectives of strategy-makers. Changes in either quickly invalidate old
methods, and in that vein Luttwak argues that between 27BC to around 350AD, three
strategies were devised to defend Rome.
Geography of the Roman Empire
Geographically,
all three strategies confronted the same problem. As a ‘hollow ring’ of
territory around the Mediterranean, the Roman Empire did not benefit from
interior lines of communications, as far as land transport was concerned. A
legion took 2 months to march from Germany to Italy, and 4 months from Italy to
Syria, which meant that Roman legions could not have a rapid enough response
time to reinforce ‘crisis points’ on a whim.
There was
sea transport, of course, but this was unavailable during the stormy winter and
unreliable the rest of the time. Generally speaking, it was only worthwhile if
times could be reduced by at least 50%, which eliminated most redeployments not
between Europe and the East.
The issue of
interior lines would not be significant if the Romans had sufficient force to
deal with any regional threats. But the restrictive nature of Roman citizenship
and by extension legionary manpower, as well as the cost and risk involved with
putting armies under distant commanders, put constraints on the size of the
Roman army. So from the 1st to the 3rd centuries, Rome’s
military power consisted of 28-30 legions totaling about 150,000 legionaries
and the same number of auxilia, and it was with this force that Roman leaders
sought to secure 6,000 km of border.
I. The
Julio-Claudian System: Partial Security and the Client System
The early
Emperors confronted a landscape dominated by the Late Republic’s dramatic
expansion, which had added Northern Spain, Gaul, the Danube Valley, Numidia and
most of the Roman East to what was now the Empire. In order to properly
garrison these regions against revolts and hostile neighbors, the army was
compelled to spread itself out; but doing so would eliminate the possibility of
further expansion, and perhaps even project Roman weakness and invite foreign
invasion. The Romans wanted the best of both worlds – internal security and
external expansion – and in order to get it, they used the client-state system
that was a holdover from the Republican period.
Sited on the
frontiers or, in the case of client-tribes, beyond the frontier, client-states were
a key part of early Imperial border security. With their limited military and
diplomatic autonomy, clients were to deal with low-intensity raiding and
control their unruly neighbors. Against high-intensity invasions, they would
absorb the initial blows and then contribute towards the Roman response. In
either case, clients were to sacrifice their own wealth and well-being first,
far before any Roman wealth, well-being and most importantly, prestige were put
on the line. Their reward for all this could be as simple as yet another delay
of their annexation.
With clients
managing the frontiers, Roman forces were therefore freed from garrison duty,
increasing the disposable force Rome had to deter enemies and acquire more
clients, further bolstering border security and thus creating a positive
feedback loop. Of course, one could lose control of powerful clients, but so
long as Rome maintained ‘escalation dominance’ by ensuring that any rebellion
would be comprehensively defeated through force of Roman arms, the client
system as a whole could contribute positively to Roman security.
The client
system’s economy of force also aided continued Imperial expansion:
post-conquest, security burdens that would normally tie down garrisons were
instead transferred to local clients, freeing up Roman forces for the next
campaign. Thus, Roman power extended much further than the size and mobility of
its army would initially suggest.
For example,
in an Empire possessing only 28 legions, Tiberius in AD 6 was able to use 12 to
wage war on the Marcomanni along the Rhine and Danube frontiers. While this
move resulted in a strategic vacuum that was filled in by the Illyrian Revolt,
a Dacian invasion and finally Varus’ defeat at Teutoberg Forest, the key point
here was that the Romans were able to pit almost half their army against a
single enemy, because, thanks to clients, they only needed 9 legions to hold
down the entirety of the Roman East and North Africa. A similar dynamic could
be seen in the Roman conquest of Britain, which saw the commitment of 4 legions
without much strategic effect on the Empire’s other frontiers.
The client
system had its costs, however, and autonomy naturally meant conceding some fiscal
and political rights to chieftains and kings. Clients required surveillance and
management to ensure they did their jobs, stayed loyal and didn’t cause extra
trouble, and this was not something every Emperor was capable of doing. But even
at their best, clients could not provide the security that Roman citizens
expected of their rulers, so the system was only politically acceptable in
un-Romanized areas. It was one thing for foreign subjects to suffer raids and
brigands due to client incompetence; it was another thing entirely for Romans,
or Romanized peoples, to be subject to the same indignities.
Finally, one
should also note that not every entity could be a client: they had to be
somewhat settled and not completely decentralized to be useful, which probably
puts the Germanic tribes at the extreme of client-ability.
Thus the
early Imperial client system, while efficient, was nevertheless a product of
specific political circumstances. Once these circumstances changed in the late
1stCentury, the strategy behind Roman defence had to change as well.
II. The Antonine System: Comprehensive
Security through Border Adjustments
As early as
Tiberius, but especially after Vespasian, Rome began breaking down the client
system in favor of direct rule. The extra tax was welcome, but Vespasian also
realized that clients could pose a danger to Imperial rule, given that his rise
to power was aided by the Eastern clients. In any case, few neighbors could now
be turned into clients, with Rome now adjoining established states such as
Dacia, Parthia, and the condominium of Armenia. In Western Europe, the process
of Romanization was well underway, and it was no longer possible to rely on the
second-grade security provided by clients for these subjects, especially as
doing so could prompt them to support usurpers such as Vitellius in Germania.
Without
clients, Rome would be solely responsible for security provision. Tactically,
the Empire would leverage its military superiority to preempt enemy threats
before they reached the minimally-fortified frontier. Strategically, however,
this would mean that the Roman army would spread itself out in a way that would
cover all imperial frontiers, sacrificing its disposable force and foregoing
any more continuous, large-scale expansion. More legions could be drawn from
the now-pacified interior, but Rome would still have to contend with the
Empire’s unfavorable geography and its army’s lack of strategic mobility.
Thus with
the goal of comprehensive security in mind, Emperors began a campaign of border
adjustment, seeking frontiers which would generate the most defensiveness at
least cost. Not all of the new borders resulted in fortifications or – in the
Syrian or Saharan deserts, garrisoning key oases was enough – but in all cases,
the goal was to repel all low- and medium-intensity threats that could
conceivably disrupt Pax Romana.
‘Defensiveness’
was defined in two ways. Firstly, borders were set with direct considerations
of terrain, redeployment distances, and smoothing out salients in mind. One
example of this could be seen in Southern Germany: prior to 70AD, the frontier
followed the natural line of the Rhine and Danube, which resulted in a 170-mile
wedge centered on the Neckar Valley – clearly an ideal route for an invader
heading towards the Alpine passes to take. Over a hundred-year period, Emperors
reduced the salient in phases, anchoring the northern edge at the Taunus
Mountains and delineating a roughly L-shaped border from Mainz to Nuremberg.
Not only did this new border shorten Germania-Moesia redeployment times by 10
days, forts on the Taunus could also give advance warning regarding potential
westward invasions of the Germanic tribes. Septimius Severus’ establishment of
a Roman salient at the head of the Euphrates and Tigris could also be seen in
this light, since it added depth to Roman Syria, provided a safe route into
Parthian Mesopotamia, as well as outflanked any Parthian westward invasions.
Secondly and
less obviously, ‘defensiveness’ also took into account the effects that the new
borders had on neighboring entities. A positive example of this would be Dacia,
obtained as part of Trajan’s conquering spree. Despite it being a huge salient,
Rome retained Dacia as eliminating the Dacians removed a serious competitor for
influence over the Central European tribes. Doing so also separated the
Danubian Sarmatians from each other, keeping them weak enough to come under
Roman control and thus indirectly shielding the Balkans. On the other hand, a
negative example could be abandoning Scotland and later the Antonine Wall in
favor of Hadrian’s Wall, due to the difficulty of controlling the unruly tribes
there.
No matter
the defensiveness of the new borders, the spreading out of the Roman Empire, as
demanded by the strategy of comprehensive security, carried with it distinct
costs. Rome no longer had the disposable force to force compliance beyond its
borders, which meant that Roman security now depended on the strength of the
legions on any given sector. If the legion responsible was redeployed or
defeated, the resultant security vacuum could result in a disastrous
self-reinforcing loop, wherein new troops would have to be redeployed in order
to counter invasion, thus creating more security vacuums, and so on. Trajan’s
Mesopotamian campaign, for example, ended in near-disaster as he stripped the
Roman East of troops, which allowed the Jews, which in the earlier system had
been pacified through Herod’s client kingdom, to revolt for the second time in
50 years.
The existence
of this potential feedback loop meant that the Empire’s pre-deployment of its
forces was of paramount importance. As the 3rd Century dawned,
Rome’s forces were still arranged in a way that presupposed unorganized tribes
on its European frontiers and a weak Parthia to its East. The former assumption
was already coming apart with Marcus Aurelius’ Marcomannic Wars, and after
Parthia was replaced by the Sassanid Empire in the 220s, the system was tested
to destruction.
III. The Late Imperial System: Imperial
Security and Defence-in-Depth (or was it?)
Beginning in
230, Sassanid Persia began the first of a long series of wars with Rome.
Facing, for the first time in a while, a centralized enemy threatening the
entirety of the Roman East, legion after legion was drawn from Europe to meet
high-intensity Sassanid assaults. Security vacuums began to appear in Rome’s
European frontiers, and were quickly filled by Germanic and Gothic invasions.
Even without
foreign invasion, the fragility of the Imperial structure was fully laid bare
during the Crisis of the Third Century. With civil war, assassination, and
usurpation the order of the day, the Emperor’s priorities became detached from
the Empire’s priorities. It was no longer prudent for an Emperor to assign large
forces to guard distant frontiers; he needed them close to himself.
The result
was the expansion of imperial guards into central field armies, a strategically
wasteful invention given the army’s low mobility. Thus, despite a ballooning of
the late Roman army to 500-700 thousand soldiers, invasions continued to occur
on a near-regular basis as weak frontier garrisons were no longer a match for
the increasingly developed Germanic and Gothic confederations.
Luttwak
argues that this combination of regular invasion and politically-necessary
central field armies found its logical strategy in a ‘defence-in-depth’ system.
Rather than previous systems, which sought to prevent large-scale invasion into
Roman territory, defence-in-depth accepts this as a fact and aims to contain
the enemy, exhaust it and eventually defeat it with reinforcing units. In Roman
terms, Luttwak outlines a system of local forts, held by semi-professional but
territorialized forces, and a goal of delaying or denying the enemy for as long
as possible before reinforcements arrive on the scene.
The success
of a ‘defence-in-depth’ ultimately still relies on the success of the field
army. If it is destroyed – like at Abrittus in 251 or at Adrianople at 378 –
then the various obstacles would only delay the inevitable, and for the Romans
there would have been little else to do but to pay the enemy off.
Luttwak’s
‘defence in depth’ system has never been supported by archaeological evidence,
which suggests that the Romans never really abandoned the goal of comprehensive
security, and instead were slowly overwhelmed by simultaneous pressure from
Persia and Germania, and later the Hunnic and Gothic invasions. Certainly, even
Luttwak agrees that in periods of stability such as under Diocletian or
Constantine, the Romans re-concentrated their forces on their frontiers,
consistent with the idea of comprehensive defence.
Both systems
of ‘defence-in-depth’ and comprehensive depth would have been in line with the
strategic retreat conducted by late Rome. Rome no longer had real control over
neighboring peoples, and given the desperate situation during the Crisis,
forward positions had to be abandoned in order to reduce imperial overstretch.
In such a way, Rome retreated from forward positions such as Numidia and
Southern Germany and abandoned the exposed salient of Dacia.
Finally,
‘defence-in-depth’ views the strategic costs that the Empire accepted during
the period as part of a broader strategy, as opposed to under comprehensive
security where it largely comes about due to policy failure. One could argue
that, from the perspective of the average Roman citizen, the question was moot:
should the repeated ransacking, evacuations and general unhappiness not be enough
to reduce faith in the Empire as an effective provider of security, then the
high taxes needed for new forts, armies and tributes would clearly do it, and
it wouldn’t matter much if this came about due to a hardhearted Imperial
decision to trade land for time or because the Empire was unable to hold the
line.
Still, such
costs were bearable if the alternative was anarchy. But once the Germans and
Goths became providers of even rudimentary governance, then the incentive to
maintain the onerous Imperial structure quickly fell away. This may explain the
survival of the Eastern Empire, which had a about 60% of its force in
territorial defence, compared with the Western Empire, which devoted 40% to
defending its citizens.
Conclusion
It is easy,
especially for those accustomed to economic rationalism or cost-benefit
analysis, to see the client-system as an ‘optimal’ strategy. But this overlooks
the political circumstances that made such a system viable in the first place.
Similarly, one could criticize the development of central field armies in the
third system was strategically wasteful, but it is unreasonable for Emperors
not to consider their personal security when making any decision during that
turbulent time. Strategy divorced from political realities are ineffective at
best and disingenuous at worst.
Turning back
to Rome, one could argue that the client system and the comprehensive system
addressed the security needs of the Empire and, to some extent, the subjects
who collectively sustained the structure of the Empire. Conversely, the
sacrifice of the broader population’s safety in favor of the Emperor’s safety
was a tradeoff that could perhaps be justified in the medium-term, but grew
increasingly self-serving and divorced from political demands as security
issues remained unaddressed. Ultimately, once rival states found cheaper and
more effective security strategies, the rationale for keeping the Western
Empire afloat faded away and Rome met its doom.
Thanks for
watching the video!
No comments:
Post a Comment